Crisis pathologies: Negative interest rates, or more lessons of the 1930s for the 2010s

January 29, 2016

Kevin Carmichael has already commented on the Bank of Japan’s (BoJ) announcement today that it is joining the European Central Bank (ECB), the Swiss National Bank and the central banks of Denmark and Sweden in charging a negative interest rate on commercial bank reserves. (The BoJ will not apply the negative rate on all reserves, just new deposits.) Martin Sandbu has an interesting perspective on the BoJ’s decision here. With Japan added to their ranks, countries with negative rates now account for nearly a quarter of the global economy. What is going on here?

Avid readers of Paul Krugman’s blog know that a conceivable answer is the possibility that full-employment levels of savings and investment may only balance at negative real interest rates. This is illustrated in the diagram below, which represents the intersection of an upward sloping savings function S(YF,r) showing how full employment level of savings respond to the real interest rate, r, and a downward sloping investment function, I(r). There isn’t a lot of theory here. In fact, the savings and investment schedules depicted are decidedly simple.[1] Nevertheless, they help illustrate a situation in which the real interest rate that “clears” the market for loanable funds is negative, at r0:

haley_blog_post_equation_0.png

Now, prior to the crisis, Ben Bernanke (then chairman of the Federal Reserve Board) warned that the global economy was suffering from a “global savings glut.” In part, this glut might result from the “forced” savings of Chinese citizens reflected, say, in large current account surpluses and foreign exchange accumulation. Absent the savings glut, the argument goes, the savings function S(YF) would be positioned closer to the vertical axis, intersecting the investment function at a positive rate of interest. Alternatively, it might be argued that investment is too low owing, perhaps, to a lack of innovation. (Could Robert Gordon be right? Or, is this consistent with Larry Summers’ fears of secular stagnation?) With greater investment possibilities the investment schedule would be shifted to the right, resulting in an equilibrium with a higher, positive real interest rate.Some might scoff that this is far too simplistic an approach; that reality is more complicated. They may well be right. But the point is that the model—which Classical as well as Keynesian economists should agree on—doesn’t rule out the possibility, a priori.

This is, clearly, a fanciful thought experiment given the parsimony (and lack of realism) of the model. The purpose of a model is to strip away complication to allow for informed conjecture and, importantly, refutation. For now, it might be helpful to think of the pathologies that might result if we relax the full employment assumption in the situation described in the graph above. To achieve full employment, we would need to have negative real rates. With nominal rates already very low and inflationary expectations once again trending down, however, the zero lower bound on nominal rates becomes binding. Recalling that the real rate of interest is the nominal rate less the expected rate of inflation:

r= i-πe,

where i is the nominal rate and πe is expected inflation, we would have a real problem if deflation rears its ugly head. Why? Because deflation is negative inflation, real interest rates would move higher, not lower. And if output is already below its full employment level (as assumed), deflationary pressures would increase further. But further deflation would drive the economy even further from the full employment equilibrium, creating even higher real interest rates.

This scenario is, I think, what leads some, such as Joe Stiglitz, to argue that the world suffers from a global lack of investment—for whatever reason (Keynes’ animal spirits perhaps? Or my preferred explanation pervasive uncertainty and the option value of waiting in which firms are loath to invest and households fearing for the future save, holding off on consumption). The policy recommendation in such circumstances is clear: Governments should exploit the opportunity afforded by historically low interest rates to investment in the infrastructure needed to cope with an ageing population, relieve congestion in key transportation modes, making the economy more productive, and address climate change.

Whatever the explanation, it is certain that the crisis pathologies that are the legacy of the Great Recession, or “Lesser Depression,” as Bard DeLong prefers, will continue to cloud the prospects for the global economy in the New Age of Uncertainty.

[1] For simplicity, start with the closed economy national income identity, Y = C + I + G, where Y represents output (GDP), C is consumption, I is investment and G is government purchases. Rearrange to isolate investment and adding and subtracting taxes, T yields S = (YF – T – C) + (T – G) = I. This expresses total savings, S, as the sum of private savings, defined by the full employment level of output less taxes (=disposal income) minus consumption, (YF – T – C), plus government savings, or tax revenue less government expenditures (T-G). The investment schedule, meanwhile, which reflects the discounting of future cash flows from investing, the can be derived as described in an earlier blog post: Large Scale Asset Purchases, Keynes’ Internal Rate of Return and the New Age of Uncertainty.

The opinions expressed in this article/multimedia are those of the author(s) and do not necessarily reflect the views of CIGI or its Board of Directors.

About the Author

James A. Haley is a senior fellow at CIGI and a Canada Institute global fellow at the Woodrow Wilson Center for International Scholars in Washington, DC.